Rand, Ayn – Capitalism

though they lost some of the best things in life [Trevelyan does not explain what he means], gained independence. . . . The money they earned was their own. The factory hand acquired an economic position personal to herself, which in the course of time other women came to envy.

And Trevelyan concluded: “The working class home often became more comfortable, quiet and sanitary by ceasing to be a miniature factory.9

Critics of the factory system still try to argue that the domestic spinners or weavers could have a creator’s pride in their work, which they lost by becoming mere cogs in a huge industrial complex. Dr. Dorothy George easily demolishes this thesis: “It seems unlikely that the average weaver, toiling

‘London: Rockliff, 1958, p. 190. ‘Ibid., pp. 192, 194.

9 George M. Trevelyan, English Social History, New York and London: Longmans, Green & Company, 1942, p. 487.

hour after hour throwing the shuttle backwards and forwards

on work which was monotonous and exhausting, had the

reactions which would satisfy a modern enthusiast for peas

ant arts.”10 *

Finally, it was charged that factory work made women too concerned with material comforts at the expense of spiritual considerations.

The misery in which women lived before capitalism might have made them cherish the New Testament injunction-Love not the world, nor the things that are in the world.” But the productive splendor of capitalism vanquished that view. Today, the foremost champions of that viewpoint are Professor Galbraith and the austerity-preachers behind the Iron Curtain.

fIO..M- Dorothy George, England in Transition: Life and Work in the Eighteenth Century, London: Penguin, 1953, p. 139.

9. THE ASSAULT ON INTEGRITY

BY ALAN GREENSPAN

Protection of the consumer against “dishonest and unscrupulous business practices” has become a cardinal ingredient of welfare statism. Left to their own devices, it is alleged, businessmen would attempt to sell unsafe food and drugs, fraudulent securities, and shoddy buildings. Thus, it is argued, the Pure Food and Drug Administration, the Securities and Exchange Commission, and the numerous building regulatory agencies are indispensable if the consumer is to be protected from the “greed” of the businessman.

But it is precisely the “greed” of the businessman or, more appropriately, his profit-seeking, which is the unexcelled protector of the consumer.

What collectivists refuse to recognize is that it is in the self-interest of every businessman to have a reputation for honest dealings and a quality product. Since the market value of a going business is measured by its money-making potential, reputation or “good will” is as much an asset as its physical plant and equipment. For many a drug company, the value of its reputation, as reflected in the salability of its brand name, is often its major asset. The loss of reputation through the sale of a shoddy or dangerous product would sharply reduce the market value of the drug company, though its physical resources would remain intact. The market value of a brokerage firm is even more closely tied to its good-will assets. Securities worth hundreds of millions of dollars are traded every day over the telephone. The slightest doubt as to the trustworthiness of a broker’s word or commitment would put him out of business overnight.

Reputation, in an unregulated economy, is thus a major competitive tool. Builders who have acquired a reputation for top quality construction take the market away from their less scrupulous or less conscientious competitors. The most reputable securities dealers get the bulk of the commission busi-

The Objectivisl Newsletter, August 1963.

118

ness. Drug manufacturers and food processors vie with oi another to make their brand names synonymous with fii quality.

Physicians have to be just as scrupulous in judging tl quality of the drugs they prescribe. They, too, are in busine and compete for trustworthiness. Even the corner grocer involved: he cannot afford to sell unhealthy foods if he wan to make money. In fact, in one way or another, evei producer and distributor of goods or services is caught up i the competition for reputation;

It requires years of consistently excellent performance 1 acquire a reputation and to establish it as a financial asse Thereafter, a still greater effort is required to maintain it: company cannot afford to risk its years of investment b letting down its standards of quality for one moment or or inferior product; nor would it be tempted by any potenth “quick killing.” Newcomers entering the field cannot compel immediately with the established, reputable companies, an have to spend years working on a more modest scale in ordc to earn an equal reputation. Thus the incentive to scrupulou performance operates on all levels of a given field of produc tion. It is a built-in safeguard of a free enterprise system an the only real protection of consumers against business dishor esty.

Government regulation is not an alternative means c protecting the consumer. It does not build quality into good; or accuracy into information. Its sole “contribution” is t substitute force and fear for incentive as the “protector” o the consumer. The euphemisms of government press release to the contrary notwithstanding, the basis of regulation i armed force. At the bottom of the endless pile of paper wor] which characterizes all regulation lies a gun. What are th results?

To paraphrase Gresham’s Law: bad “protection” drive out good. The attempt to protect the consumer by foro undercuts the protection he gets from incentive. First, i undercuts the value of reputation by placing the reputabl company on the same basis as the unknown, the newcomer or the fly-by-nighter. It declares, in effect, that all are equall; suspect and that years of evidence to the contrary do not frei a man from that suspicion. Second, it grants an automatii (though, in fact, unachievable) guarantee of safety to thi products of any company that complies with its arbitrarily se minimum standards. The value of a reputation rested on th< fact that it was necessary for the consumers to exercise judgment in the choice of the goods and services they pur chased. The government's "guarantee" undermines this necessity; it declares to the consumers, in effect, that no choice or judgment is required—and that a company's record, its years of achievement, is irrelevant. The minimum standards, which are the basis of regulation, gradually tend to become the maximums as well. If the building codes set minimum standards of construction, a builder does not get very much competitive advantage by exceeding those standards and, accordingly, he tends to meet only the minimums. If minimum specifications are set for vitamins, there is little profit in producing something of above-average quality. Gradually, even the attempt to maintain minimum standards becomes impossible, since the draining of incentives to improve quality ultimately undermines even the minimums. The guiding purpose of the government regulator is to prevent rather than to create something. He gets no credit if a new miraculous drug is discovered by drug company scientists; he does if he bans thalidomide. Such emphasis on the negative sets the framework under which even the most conscientious regulators must operate. The result is a growing body of restrictive legislation on drug experimentation, testing, and distribution. As in all research, it is impossible to add restrictions to the development of new drugs without simultaneously cutting off the secondary rewards of such research—the improvement of existing drugs. Quality improvement and innovation are inseparable. Building codes are supposed to protect the public. But by being forced to adhere to standards of construction long after they have been surpassed by new technological discoveries, builders divert their efforts to maintaining the old rather than adopting new and safer techniques of construction. Regulation—which is based on force and fear— undermines the moral base of business dealings. It becomes cheaper to bribe a building inspector than to meet his standards of construction. A fly-by-night securities operator can quickly meet all the S.E.C. requirements, gain the inference of respectability, and proceed to fleece the public. In an unregulated economy, the operator would have had to spend a number of years in reputable dealings before he could earn a position of trust sufficient to induce a number of investors to place funds with him. Protection of the consumer by regulation is thus illusory. Rather than isolating the consumer from the dishonest businessman, it is gradually destroying the only reliable protec- tion the consumer has: competition for reputation. While the consumer is thus endangered, the major victim of "protective" regulation is the producer: the businessman. Regulation which acts to destroy the competition of businessmen for reputation undermines the market value of the good will which businessmen have built up over the years. It is an act of expropriation of wealth created by integrity. Since the value of a business—its wealth—rests on its ability to make money, the acts of a government seizing a company's plant or devaluing its reputation are in the same category: both are acts of expropriation. Moreover, "protective" legislation falls in the category of preventive law. Businessmen are being subjected to governmental coercion prior to the commission of any crime. In a free economy, the government may step in only when a fraud has been perpetrated, or a demonstrable damage has been done to a consumer; in such cases the only protection required is that of criminal law.

Pages: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85

Leave a Reply 0

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *